Friday, August 17, 2012

What's Really Missing In The Ryan Budget


On August 16, 2012, Daniel Mitchell published an article in the Wall Street Journal under the title “What's Really in the Ryan Budget” and the subtitle: “Good fiscal policy requires the private sector to grow faster than the government. That is the crucial goal of the House Republican budget.” And this is basically what sums up the essence of the article. Rather than blame one party or the other for the economic difficulties which America is facing at this time, the author blames both the Bush and Obama administrations for what he calls “the spending spree that's put America in a fiscal ditch.”

But he promises that the Ryan budget adopted by the House Republicans will fix all that. And the promise rests on the fact that the private sector will be put in charge of the economy which, according to him, is good news because “what matters for prosperity ... is the degree to which labor and capital are used productively. This is why policy makers should focus on … leaving more resources in the private economy.” What is meant by this is that the private economy is more efficient than government. Well, this may be true – more or less some of the time -- but is not always as relevant as we would like it to be.

One of the mistakes that people make is that they automatically associate growth in the economy with efficiency as if there exists a cause and effect relationship between the two. But the fact is that no such relationship exists, and the proof is that you can have a jobless recovery such as the one we are having at this time. Thus, the reality is that the two conditions of growth and efficiency can coexist or they can exist separately. Both can also be missing, or one may coexist with the opposite of the other. That is, it can happen that growth will coexist with inefficiency, or that stagnation will coexist with efficiency. In short, any combination is possible, and this is why the attempt to forecast the exact performance of an economy is almost always an exercise in futility.

Yet, what Mitchell does throughout the article is discuss his forecast and those of others when in fact, all that we can do -- if and when a new policy is contemplated -- is to envisage the broad outlines of what the policy may accomplish, and no more. This means we cannot tell ahead of time exactly where the unemployment level will be, or where the growth rate will sit as a result of an action we may take. The reason why we almost always go wrong in our forecasts is that we can only talk about a sliver of the economy not knowing how the sliver relates to the whole because we can never have a grip on all the factors that enter into the equation. This is a point I shall return to a little later on.

Yes, what most people advocate is correct, mainly that the government must work to reduce the national debt and the deficit. But how this can be done without hurting the economy more than it is already hurting is a question we cannot always answer with certainty. To see why this is so, we must realize that the economy is made of two parts; the part that constitutes the production side of the economic engine, and the part that constitutes the consumption side. Unaware of this fundamental reality, most people do not realize that there exists a constant interplay between the two parts, let alone know what goes on in there.

To take an example, two knowledgeable people could have a discussion on radio or television that goes this way: When you give a tax break to the rich, you encourage them to modernize their businesses. This will cause their operation to be more efficient, something that will lead to a higher growth for the business, and for the economy as a whole. When this happens, more money can be raised through taxation without hiking the tax rate. This will help reduce the deficit immediately, and reduce the national debt in the long run. Well, someone listening to this conversation who may not be as well versed in economic matters will be prompted – as it often happens -- to go around and echo the following: The rich produce the wealth; give them more money and they will solve all our problems.

Unfortunately, this cannot always be true. What is missing in that narrative is the fact that the part of the economic engine which produces the goods and the services cannot keep producing if the part which consumes those goods and services is unable to consume all that is being produced. When this happens – as when it is dictated by the economic cycle and other factors -- you get a bottleneck that forces the engine to slow down. This is simple enough to understand, but where it gets complicated is when you introduce the notion that the economic engine must also dedicate some of its output to do more than just feed the consuming part.

The thing is that every operation needs to allocate resources to do some repair work and some maintenance as well as do the occasional renovation, even expand when it is so desired. If we are talking about the national economy, expansion is always desired to avoid being hit with stagnation and unemployment. In this context, expansion means the production of more goods and/or services next year than were produced this year. That is, what is needed is to register a growth in the economy that will at least match the growth in the population if not exceed it by a little or even a lot.

When it comes to determining how much maintenance is needed for a business operation, there is generally little difficulty here because when a machine breaks down, we know what new parts will be needed, and what sort of repair crew will work on it. But when it comes to determining how much of the economic output should be set aside for use to expand the national economy and register the desired growth -- well, this is a different matter. What must not be forgotten when working the math in such cases is a phenomenon called diminishing returns. In plain English, it says that you cannot keep handing money to the rich and expect them to grow the economy by the same proportion. What will happen is that a point will be reached where the throwing of more money at the rich will yield lesser and lesser results, till you get zero return.

And this brings us to the definition of the word efficiency. To be efficient in a business operation is to obtain a larger output even as you feed the input with the regular amount or less of it. A word that is often used by mathematicians to mean the attainment of maximum efficiency is “optimization.” The branch of mathematics that allows you to find the optimum point of a process is called differential calculus. The difficulty here is that you can find the optimum point of a process only if you can set up the correct equation. This is usually done with ease in geometry and in science where the number of variables are limited, and can easily be determined. But the same cannot be said about economics or the other human activities because the number of variables involved is unlimited, and every situation has a unique combination of them. This necessitates that you determine a unique equation for each situation, something that is almost always impossible to get exactly right.

In fact, there exists, right now, a number of equations in the memory banks of many a government computer describing all sorts of economies that happen to stand at a different level of their development, and a different point in their cycle. But these are approximate equations that will only yield an indication as to how an economy may respond to a policy decision but will not yield an exact answer. To get a sense of what is involved here, consider the following example in geometry – the simplest I could think of:

You have a string that is 12 feet in length. You need to make an enclosure, other than a circle, that will optimize the surface area of the enclosure. What dimensions should you give the rectangle you make with that string? Well, given that the surface of a rectangle is determined by multiplying one side called the length by the other side called the width, you reason that one length and one width will have to be 6 feet long – half the perimeter of the rectangle. Not knowing how to set up an equation let alone solve it, you look for the answer by the method of trial and error.

To this end, you make the length equal to 5 feet, and make the width equal to 1 foot. Multiplying the two numbers gives the surface area of the enclosure as being 5 square feet. You now try 4 and 2, thus get the result 8 square feet which is a greater value than before. You now try 3 and 3 to get the result of 9 square feet which is an even greater value. And you realize that this will have to be the optimum point because to go further is to reverse the operation and get the same results in the reverse order. Thus, the rectangle that has the optimum surface area in this type of problems is actually the square -- where the length and the width are equal.

Instead of experimenting as we did here, an equation could have been written and solved by differentiation, and it would have given the same answer. This being a simple problem, it was possible to arrive at the answer by trial and error, something that could not be done with more complicated problems. This is why calculus was invented, but here too, calculus will do well when solving problems of geometry or science. However, it will never do as well when trying to solve economic problems or the other situations where human nature is involved. This is because the factors are endless – most of which we don't even know about. Try as we may, the answer will never be exactly right.

Well then, absent a scientific way to determine how we can optimize the growth of the economy without getting caught in a situation of diminishing return, what is there to do? To be sure, this is a serious question, and the answer is that you should experiment. What is meant by this is not that you do an experiment in the lab and apply the result somewhere else. Rather, it means that the management of the national economy must be a continuous experimentation; a never ending process of trial and error. With it comes the predicate that accompanies every experiment, and the risks that result from it.

The predicate is that you will need to have flexibility when you take on the task of solving the economic problems of the nation. This will be necessary given that you will proceed blindly as if walking through a minefield. As to the risk, it is that flexibility will require the suppression of the checks and balances that can tie the hands of the czar or the committee in charge of conducting the experiment. Such suppression will be necessary because decisions will have to be taken on the spot when the experiment starts to go wrong, and decisions will have to be executed without delay.

The central bank has this kind of flexibility as well as the authority to act on a weekly, even daily basis when necessary. It does well when the economy is running normally or running a little out of whack. But when the economy goes very bad, the central bank alone cannot solve the complex problems that ensue because the treasury has a part to play as well. However, in a democracy -- or what passes for one -- the treasury is overseen by the legislature and by the rest of the executive branch. This slows the decision making process so much that fixing the economy becomes a difficult thing, if not an impossible thing to accomplish. Thus, the economy is left alone to fix itself most of the time, something that takes a long time to do.

What is needed instead, is that a czar or a small committee be given a broad and flexible mandate, and put in charge of running the economy till it is fixed, after which things are returned to their normal state. As to the Mitchell view that: “the Ryan budget … limits the growth rate of federal spending, with outlays increasing by an average of 3.1% annually … If spending is left on autopilot ... it would grow by 4.3%” cannot be seen to change anything because it still reflects a rigid approach with no provision to navigate around the waves that hit the economy on a daily basis.

What is needed, therefore, is the release of the central or federal treasurer from any constraints so as to act alone when necessary, or act in conjunction with the central banker. The two should also be able to suggest to the chief executive and to the ministries or the departments what else needs to be done to get the nation back on its feet.

And everyone will have to work together on fine tuning the economic machine on a daily basis to get the exact balance between the production side, the consumption side and what must be set aside to provide for maintenance and for growth without wasting anything on diminishing returns.