Wednesday, May 13, 2020

Think of the dough-kneading economic machine

Did you ever look at a dough-kneading machine at work? If you did, you'll have no trouble understanding why it is impossible to predict how a measure that we take, will affect the economy.

That's because––like the dough in the machine––the economy is simultaneously squeezed at one side and pulled at another side while being twirled round and round by the activities of all of us who are both the producers and consumers of the economy.

Thus, any action taken by the treasury or the central bank, will change the long-term performance of the economy as much as you would change the outcome if you added a pinch of flour or a drop of water to the dough while the machine is working it.

Does that mean there is no use thinking about the economy, since it is going to do what it wants anyway? No. It does not mean that. What it means is that while we may be confounded by the response of the economy to measures that we take now and then, we can still have a clear picture of how the economy operates at the fundamental level. This is to say that while the dough in the machine will do what it wants, it will become the loaf of bread we meant it to be, when all is said and done.

It's a good thing to have that in mind when assessing the validity of what is said during the ongoing debate regarding what needs to be done with the debts that almost every government is incurring to mitigate the effects of the COVID-19 pandemic. There is no doubt that sooner or later, coronavirus will be eliminated, but the debts will still be here. The important question, therefore, is what to do to mitigate or eliminate the lingering effect of the debt loads caused by the pandemic.

Willis L. Krunholz offers a number of ideas in the article he wrote under the title: “How Trillion-Dollar Deficits Kill Blue-Collar America, And Coronavirus Bailouts Make It Worse,” and the subtitle: “Because of the coronavirus bailouts, the federal deficit is now expected to be $3.7 trillion for fiscal 2020. This is a huge drag on Americans' earnings and retirement security.” It was published on May 11, 2020 in The Federalist.

But since we cannot rely on economists to reveal what we already know, which is that the economic dough in the kneading machine will be “on the one hand” squeezed this way, and on the “other hand” pulled that way –– we'll have to go to the fundamentals of things and look for answers there.

Furthermore, we need to remember that it will do no good to look for the fundamentals that have been in circulation for decades, and rehash them. It's because doing so will take us to the one hand of one economist or the other hand of another economist, and we'll all be back to square one. We must therefore leave that box altogether, and think outside of it to breathe the fresh air of a new economic model.

In the American case, adding nearly $4 trillion of deficit to the debt that's already there, is something that must be dealt with seriously because in the way that it is unhealthy for individuals and families to be highly indebted, it is so with the nation as a whole. But what is a national debt? It is money that's borrowed by the government in the name of the population. The principal and interest are paid back to the lenders with taxes that the government collects from the population.

The analogy is often made about the country whose GDP is valued at $20 trillion, sitting on a $20 trillion debt––as being the same as a family earning $100 thousand a year and sitting on a debt valued at $100 thousand. Well, part of that is true, and part is not. It's because a government borrows from foreigners and from its own citizens. What it borrows from foreigners is the same as a family borrowing from a financial institution such as a bank. But when the government borrows from its citizens, it is said that, “We're borrowing from ourselves”.

In fact, this part of the analogy too is partially true and partially false. That's because the truth can better be expressed as follows: “Some of us who need it, borrow from some of us that have a surplus to lend.” But what does that mean in practical terms? To answer this question, we need to illustrate with examples.

Imagine country “A” being self-sufficient in everything when the climate conditions are right, but never has a surplus of anything it can export. Unfortunately, once in a while the country experiences drought or hurricane or volcanic eruption, and finds itself short of one commodity or another. It borrows from abroad to buy what it needs. Time after time, it adds to the debt by borrowing even more to pay back the old debt and the accumulated interests. This means that the debt load keeps increasing and never diminishes.

Now imagine country “B” also being self-sufficient in everything and blessed with perfect climate conditions all the time, which makes it so that the country does not need to borrow from abroad. But lo and behold, it borrows from itself. That is, it borrows from some of its citizens in the name of all the citizens. It does so, not because the population does not produce enough to fill the needs of everyone; it does. But the problem is that the distribution of the money that’s printed to represent the wealth, is distributed unevenly among the population. This makes some citizens ultra-rich, and others ultra-poor, and that's what compels the government to borrow from the rich in the name of all, and spends it on the poor, most of whom are the ones producing the wealth that the ultra-rich are allowed to accumulate using a rigged system.

The current situation in many countries is that approximately one percent of the population owns most of the wealth in the country, in addition to being owed a year's worth of sweat and toil by the entire population. This is pornographic insanity that needs to be addressed.

It so happened over the last few decades that several countries were unable to pay back the debts they had accumulated. Two or three centuries ago, the lender would have sent an expeditionary force to occupy the home of the borrower and loot it of its natural resources. This did not happen during the last few decades, however. Instead, the lenders forgave some of the debt while institutions such as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund also helped in several ways.

There is a lesson here for what to do with a national debt that is no longer tolerated. The part that is owed to foreigners must be paid back when possible. The part that is owed to local lenders must be substantially eliminated (as in forgiven,) but done so over time. There are many ways to accomplish this feat. The best way, in my view, is for the treasury to stop issuing debt instruments to begin with. And then, authorized by Congress, the government will borrow what it needs from the Fed at zero interest and no obligation to pay back the principal. As to the debt instruments of long maturity which are floating out there, the government will buy them back at 90 percent of their face value the first year. This will go down to 80 percent the second year, and will continue to diminish by 10 percent year after year till the last certificate has been bought back.

Since you cannot convince many of the rich to divest themselves of what they have by donating most of what they own to the government or to charitable organizations, you must use the method of diluting what they own. The way to do this, is for the Fed to print as much as the government can distribute to the general population without any of it going to the ultra-rich.

It would be nice if all the governments around the globe got together and implemented a program such as that to dissuade the rich from threatening any one with taking their business and going elsewhere.