Friday, May 10, 2013

At Last A Plumber To Fix The Trickle Down


It is refreshing to see someone of the Martin Feldstein caliber recognize that there is a limit as to how good a good thing can be. On May 10, 2013, professor Feldstein published an article in the Wall Street Journal under the title: “The Federal Reserve's Policy Dead End” and the subtitle: “Quantitative easing hasn't led to faster growth. A better recovery depends on the White House and Congress.” The remarkable development here is that the article ends like this: “The time has come … to recognize … that a stronger recovery must depend on fiscal actions … by the White House and Congress.”

What is stunning about this view is that Mr. Feldstein has put on one side of the scale of comparison the principle of “quantitative easing” and put on the other side the principle of “fiscal actions.” He weighs the two sides intelligently, and comes to the conclusion that the scale is no longer balancing, a situation that needs to be rectified by calling on the White House and the Congress to add weight to the fiscal side of the equation.

What this does is weaken the dogmatic argument to the effect that the principle of “trickle down economics” is so absolute in its goodness, the more it is pushed to the extreme, the more effective it becomes. Thus, the more money you place in the hands of those who have it, and the less you take from them in taxes, the more the economy will tend to grow. The result will be that goodness will multiply and will trickle down to those who have little of it to begin with.

Professor Feldstein was never that extreme in his views but he often argued in favor of the production side of the economy being robust without making enough reference to the fact that the consumption side must also be robust to absorb what is being produced. This left the impression that he meant to say consumption must wait for production to trickle some of its goodness down to it thus give it enough purchasing power to consume what is produced. It may not be one hundred percent trickle down but it sounds very much like it.

Because in a modern industrial economy things are done or left undone by the way that you print and distribute money, the central bank – known in America as the Fed – becomes the ultimate decider as to how much the production side of the economy is itself supplied with money. As to the consumption side, some of that money trickles down to it in the form of wages and salaries – but money can also come to it from the government which, in America, is referred to as the White House and the Congress.

And this is the point where the debate between the supply-siders and the consumption-siders began to heat up. The point that the supply-siders kept repeating and still do, is that the money spent by government is money that comes to it in the form of taxes raised on the businesses that create jobs. And this, they say, contributes to the slowing down of the economy.

It was difficult to argue against that point till something big happened; the economy of America almost collapsed in 2008 and was followed by Europe. To rescue the world from a depression, the “Western” central bankers discovered a trick that the Japanese had made use of before them. It was for the central bank to pump money into the economy in an operation they called “quantitative easing.” That is, they said: Never mind why the money is printed, just print more of it and give to the supply-siders so that they may trickle some of it down to the consumption-siders and keep the economy going.

The approach worked for a while but then the economy not only came to a halt but could not even remain afloat. The Japanese created the metaphor of someone pushing on a string to describe the reality that the supply-siders had hit a saturation point beyond which they could not absorb more money. Without this mechanism, money could not reach the consumption side, a development that prompted the American Fed to come up with another idea. It called it “portfolio-balance,” described by Feldstein this way: “When the Fed buys long-term … securities, private investors can no longer buy them therefore buy equities. That drives up the price of equities, leading to more consumer spending.”

And when this did not work as well as expected, Feldstein has finally hinted – using different words – that if the Fed can print all it wants to supply the supply-siders with money, it can also print all it wants and supply it to the government which – by fiscal actions – will place it in the hands of the consumers. Again, using different words, he seems to argue that this will pull on the string that the Fed is no longer able to push effectively against.

And Feldstein will forever come to be known as the plumber who fixed the hole in the trickle-down dogma of economics.